• 검색 결과가 없습니다.

EPI BRIEFING PAPER E C O N O M I C P O L I C Y I N S T I T U T E • S E P T E M B E R 2 9 , 2 0 1 4 • B R I E F I N G P A P E R # 3 8 4

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "EPI BRIEFING PAPER E C O N O M I C P O L I C Y I N S T I T U T E • S E P T E M B E R 2 9 , 2 0 1 4 • B R I E F I N G P A P E R # 3 8 4"

Copied!
22
0
0

로드 중.... (전체 텍스트 보기)

전체 글

(1)

EPI BRIEFING PAPER

E C O N O M I C P O L I C Y I N S T I T U T E • S E P T E M B E R 2 9 , 2 0 1 4 • B R I E F I N G PA P E R # 3 8 4

LONG-TERM UNEMPLOYMENT HAS NOT DAMAGED THE

PRODUCTIVITY OF WORKERS

A Review of the Evidence on Long-Term Unemployment’s Lasting Effects on Workers,

Households, and the Economy

B Y J O S H B I V E N S

(2)

Table of contents

Introduction and executive summary...3

Evidence on microeconomic scarring...5

Evidence on macroeconomic scarring...13

Conclusion...19

About the author...20

Endnotes...20

References...21

(3)

Introduction and executive summary

S

ince 2009, the U.S. economy has been characterized by an elevated long-term unemployment (LTU) rate. As shown in Figure A, the share of workers who have been jobless for 27 weeks or more is elevated relative both to its historical rate and, until recently, to the short-term unemployment rate. This has justly raised concerns among many policymakers and economic observers, particularly over the degree to which long-term unemployment leads to “scarring” effects.

FIGURE A VIEW INTERACTIVE on epi.org

Short-term and long-term unemployment rates, 1979–2014

Note: The long-term unemployment rate is the share of workers who have been jobless for 27 weeks or more. Shaded areas denote recessions.

Source: EPI analysis of the Current Population Survey public data series from the Bureau of Labor Statistics

While this concern is oft-repeated, a workable definition of “scarring” has been hard to pin down. Because it is so crucial to interpreting our findings, this paper starts with our definitions of economic scarring. It then examines evidence on long-term unemployment and scarring. In particular, this paper looks at two separate categories of scarring: microeco- nomic and macroeconomic scarring. And within each, it differentiates between scarring caused by any episode of invol- untary unemployment, and scarring that is unique to episodes of elevated long-term unemployment.

Microeconomic scarring

We define microeconomic scarring stemming from any spell of job loss as the damage this episode inflicts on an individ- ual’s or household’s future economic health even after the spell of joblessness ends. Therefore, if an episode of involuntary

4.0%

2.0%

Short-term unemployment rate Long-term unemployment rate

1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015

0 10%

2.5 5 7.5 Date

Short-term unemployment

rate

Long-term unemployment

rate 1979/

01/01 5.3% 0.5%

1979/

02/01 5.4% 0.5%

1979/

03/01 5.3% 0.6%

1979/

04/01 5.3% 0.5%

1979/

05/01 5.2% 0.5%

1979/

06/01 5.2% 0.5%

1979/

07/01 5.3% 0.4%

1979/

08/01 5.5% 0.5%

1979/

09/01 5.3% 0.5%

1979/

10/01 5.4% 0.5%

1979/

11/01 5.3% 0.5%

1979/

12/01 5.4% 0.5%

1980/

01/01 5.7% 0.5%

1980/

02/01 5.8% 0.5%

1980/

03/01 5.8% 0.6%

1980/

04/01 6.3% 0.6%

1980/

05/01 6.9% 0.7%

1980/

06/01 6.8% 0.7%

1980/

07/01 6.9% 0.8%

1980/

08/01 6.8% 0.9%

1980/

09/01 6.6% 0.9%

1980/

10/01 6.5% 1.0%

1980/

11/01 6.4% 1.1%

1980/

12/01 6.1% 1.1%

1981/

01/01 6.3% 1.2%

1981/

02/01 6.3% 1.2%

1981/

03/01 6.3% 1.1%

1981/

04/01 6.2% 1.0%

1981/

05/01 6.5% 1.1%

1981/

06/01 6.3% 1.0%

1981/

07/01 6.3% 1.0%

1981/

08/01 6.3% 1.1%

1981/

09/01 6.6% 1.0%

1981/

10/01 6.9% 1.0%

1981/

11/01 7.2% 1.0%

1981/

12/01 7.5% 1.1%

1982/

01/01 7.5% 1.1%

1982/

02/01 7.7% 1.2%

1982/

03/01 7.9% 1.2%

1982/

04/01 8.0% 1.4%

1982/

05/01 8.0% 1.5%

1982/

06/01 7.9% 1.6%

1982/

07/01 8.1% 1.6%

1982/

08/01 8.2% 1.7%

1982/

09/01 8.4% 1.8%

1982/

10/01 8.4% 2.0%

1982/

11/01 8.7% 2.1%

1982/

12/01 8.5% 2.3%

1983/

01/01 8.1% 2.4%

1983/

02/01 8.0% 2.5%

1983/

03/01 7.7% 2.5%

1983/

04/01 7.5% 2.5%

1983/

05/01 7.5% 2.5%

1983/

06/01 7.3% 2.6%

1983/

07/01 7.2% 2.3%

1983/

08/01 7.3% 2.3%

1983/

09/01 7.1% 2.2%

1983/

10/01 6.8% 2.0%

1983/

11/01 6.6% 1.9%

1983/

12/01 6.5% 1.8%

1984/

01/01 6.3% 1.8%

1984/

02/01 6.2% 1.6%

1984/

03/01 6.2% 1.6%

1984/

04/01 6.1% 1.6%

1984/

05/01 5.9% 1.5%

1984/

06/01 5.8% 1.4%

1984/

07/01 6.1% 1.4%

1984/

08/01 6.2% 1.3%

1984/

09/01 6.1% 1.3%

1984/

10/01 6.1% 1.3%

1984/

11/01 5.9% 1.2%

1984/

12/01 6.1% 1.2%

1985/

01/01 6.2% 1.1%

1985/

02/01 6.1% 1.2%

1985/

03/01 6.1% 1.2%

1985/

04/01 6.1% 1.2%

1985/

05/01 6.2% 1.1%

1985/

06/01 6.2% 1.1%

1985/

07/01 6.2% 1.1%

1985/

08/01 6.1% 1.1%

1985/

09/01 6.1% 1.1%

1985/

10/01 6.1% 1.0%

1985/

11/01 5.9% 1.1%

1985/

12/01 6.0% 1.0%

1986/

01/01 5.8% 0.9%

1986/

02/01 6.2% 1.0%

1986/

03/01 6.2% 1.0%

1986/

04/01 6.2% 1.0%

1986/

05/01 6.2% 1.0%

1986/

06/01 6.1% 1.1%

1986/

07/01 6.0% 1.0%

1986/

08/01 5.9% 1.0%

1986/

09/01 6.0% 1.0%

1986/

10/01 5.9% 1.0%

1986/

11/01 5.9% 1.0%

1986/

12/01 5.7% 1.0%

1987/

01/01 5.7% 1.0%

1987/

02/01 5.7% 0.9%

1987/

03/01 5.6% 0.9%

1987/

04/01 5.4% 0.9%

1987/

05/01 5.3% 0.9%

1987/

06/01 5.3% 0.9%

1987/

07/01 5.3% 0.8%

1987/

08/01 5.1% 0.9%

1987/

09/01 5.1% 0.8%

1987/

10/01 5.2% 0.8%

1987/

11/01 5.1% 0.8%

1987/

12/01 5.0% 0.7%

1988/

01/01 5.0% 0.7%

1988/

02/01 5.0% 0.7%

1988/

03/01 5.0% 0.7%

1988/

04/01 4.8% 0.7%

1988/

05/01 4.9% 0.7%

1988/

06/01 4.7% 0.7%

1988/

07/01 4.8% 0.7%

1988/

08/01 4.9% 0.7%

1988/

09/01 4.7% 0.7%

1988/

10/01 4.7% 0.6%

1988/

11/01 4.8% 0.6%

1988/

12/01 4.7% 0.6%

1989/

01/01 4.8% 0.6%

1989/

02/01 4.7% 0.5%

1989/

03/01 4.5% 0.5%

1989/

04/01 4.7% 0.6%

1989/

05/01 4.7% 0.5%

1989/

06/01 4.8% 0.5%

1989/

07/01 4.8% 0.5%

1989/

08/01 4.7% 0.5%

1989/

09/01 4.8% 0.5%

1989/

10/01 4.8% 0.5%

1989/

11/01 4.9% 0.5%

1989/

12/01 4.8% 0.5%

1990/

01/01 4.8% 0.5%

1990/

02/01 4.8% 0.5%

1990/

03/01 4.8% 0.5%

1990/

04/01 4.9% 0.5%

1990/

05/01 4.9% 0.5%

1990/

06/01 4.8% 0.5%

1990/

07/01 5.0% 0.5%

1990/

08/01 5.1% 0.6%

1990/

09/01 5.2% 0.6%

1990/

10/01 5.3% 0.6%

1990/

11/01 5.5% 0.7%

1990/

12/01 5.6% 0.7%

1991/

01/01 5.6% 0.7%

1991/

02/01 5.8% 0.7%

1991/

03/01 6.1% 0.8%

1991/

04/01 5.9% 0.8%

1991/

05/01 6.1% 0.8%

1991/

06/01 6.1% 0.9%

1991/

07/01 5.9% 0.9%

1991/

08/01 5.9% 0.9%

1991/

09/01 5.9% 0.9%

1991/

10/01 6.0% 1.0%

1991/

11/01 6.0% 1.1%

1991/

12/01 6.1% 1.2%

1992/

01/01 6.0% 1.3%

1992/

02/01 6.1% 1.3%

1992/

03/01 6.0% 1.4%

1992/

04/01 5.9% 1.4%

1992/

05/01 6.0% 1.5%

1992/

06/01 6.2% 1.7%

1992/

07/01 6.0% 1.7%

1992/

08/01 6.0% 1.6%

1992/

09/01 6.0% 1.6%

1992/

10/01 5.7% 1.7%

1992/

11/01 5.9% 1.6%

1992/

12/01 5.9% 1.6%

1993/

01/01 5.7% 1.5%

1993/

02/01 5.7% 1.5%

1993/

03/01 5.6% 1.4%

1993/

04/01 5.7% 1.3%

1993/

05/01 5.7% 1.4%

1993/

06/01 5.7% 1.4%

1993/

07/01 5.5% 1.4%

1993/

08/01 5.4% 1.4%

1993/

09/01 5.4% 1.4%

1993/

10/01 5.5% 1.4%

1993/

11/01 5.2% 1.4%

1993/

12/01 5.2% 1.4%

1994/

01/01 5.3% 1.3%

1994/

02/01 5.2% 1.3%

1994/

03/01 5.1% 1.4%

1994/

04/01 4.9% 1.3%

1994/

05/01 4.8% 1.3%

1994/

06/01 4.9% 1.2%

1994/

07/01 4.9% 1.2%

1994/

08/01 4.9% 1.2%

1994/

09/01 4.7% 1.2%

1994/

10/01 4.6% 1.2%

1994/

11/01 4.5% 1.1%

1994/

12/01 4.4% 1.0%

1995/

01/01 4.5% 1.0%

1995/

02/01 4.5% 0.9%

1995/

03/01 4.4% 1.0%

1995/

04/01 4.6% 1.1%

1995/

05/01 4.7% 1.0%

1995/

06/01 4.6% 0.9%

1995/

07/01 4.7% 0.9%

1995/

08/01 4.8% 0.9%

1995/

09/01 4.7% 1.0%

1995/

10/01 4.6% 0.9%

1995/

11/01 4.7% 0.9%

1995/

12/01 4.7% 0.9%

1996/

01/01 4.7% 0.9%

1996/

02/01 4.6% 0.9%

1996/

03/01 4.5% 1.0%

1996/

04/01 4.5% 1.0%

1996/

05/01 4.6% 1.0%

1996/

06/01 4.3% 1.0%

1996/

07/01 4.4% 1.0%

1996/

08/01 4.2% 0.9%

1996/

09/01 4.3% 0.9%

1996/

10/01 4.4% 0.9%

1996/

11/01 4.5% 0.8%

1996/

12/01 4.4% 0.9%

1997/

01/01 4.4% 0.8%

1997/

02/01 4.4% 0.8%

1997/

03/01 4.4% 0.8%

1997/

04/01 4.2% 0.8%

1997/

05/01 4.2% 0.8%

1997/

06/01 4.2% 0.8%

1997/

07/01 4.1% 0.8%

1997/

08/01 4.1% 0.8%

1997/

09/01 4.1% 0.8%

1997/

10/01 4.0% 0.8%

1997/

11/01 3.9% 0.7%

1997/

12/01 3.9% 0.7%

1998/

01/01 3.9% 0.7%

1998/

02/01 3.9% 0.7%

1998/

03/01 4.1% 0.7%

1998/

04/01 3.7% 0.6%

1998/

05/01 3.8% 0.6%

1998/

06/01 4.0% 0.6%

1998/

07/01 3.9% 0.6%

1998/

08/01 3.9% 0.6%

1998/

09/01 3.9% 0.7%

1998/

10/01 3.9% 0.6%

1998/

11/01 3.8% 0.6%

1998/

12/01 3.7% 0.6%

1999/

01/01 3.8% 0.5%

1999/

02/01 3.8% 0.6%

1999/

03/01 3.7% 0.5%

1999/

04/01 3.9% 0.5%

1999/

05/01 3.7% 0.5%

1999/

06/01 3.7% 0.6%

1999/

07/01 3.7% 0.5%

1999/

08/01 3.7% 0.5%

1999/

09/01 3.7% 0.5%

1999/

10/01 3.6% 0.5%

1999/

11/01 3.6% 0.5%

1999/

12/01 3.5% 0.5%

2000/

01/01 3.5% 0.5%

2000/

02/01 3.6% 0.4%

2000/

03/01 3.7% 0.5%

2000/

04/01 3.5% 0.4%

2000/

05/01 3.6% 0.5%

2000/

06/01 3.5% 0.4%

2000/

07/01 3.5% 0.5%

2000/

08/01 3.6% 0.5%

2000/

09/01 3.5% 0.5%

2000/

10/01 3.5% 0.4%

2000/

11/01 3.5% 0.4%

2000/

12/01 3.5% 0.4%

2001/

01/01 3.7% 0.5%

2001/

02/01 3.8% 0.5%

2001/

03/01 3.9% 0.5%

2001/

04/01 4.0% 0.5%

2001/

05/01 3.9% 0.4%

2001/

06/01 3.9% 0.5%

2001/

07/01 4.0% 0.5%

2001/

08/01 4.3% 0.6%

2001/

09/01 4.4% 0.6%

2001/

10/01 4.7% 0.6%

2001/

11/01 4.8% 0.8%

2001/

12/01 5.0% 0.8%

2002/

01/01 4.9% 0.8%

2002/

02/01 4.8% 0.8%

2002/

03/01 4.9% 0.9%

2002/

04/01 5.0% 1.0%

2002/

05/01 4.7% 1.1%

2002/

06/01 4.7% 1.1%

2002/

07/01 4.7% 1.1%

2002/

08/01 4.7% 1.1%

2002/

09/01 4.6% 1.1%

2002/

10/01 4.6% 1.1%

2002/

11/01 4.7% 1.2%

2002/

12/01 4.7% 1.3%

2003/

01/01 4.7% 1.2%

2003/

02/01 4.6% 1.3%

2003/

03/01 4.6% 1.2%

2003/

04/01 4.7% 1.3%

2003/

05/01 4.8% 1.3%

2003/

06/01 4.8% 1.4%

2003/

07/01 4.8% 1.3%

2003/

08/01 4.8% 1.4%

2003/

09/01 4.7% 1.4%

2003/

10/01 4.6% 1.3%

2003/

11/01 4.5% 1.4%

2003/

12/01 4.4% 1.3%

2004/

01/01 4.4% 1.3%

2004/

02/01 4.3% 1.3%

2004/

03/01 4.4% 1.4%

2004/

04/01 4.3% 1.2%

2004/

05/01 4.4% 1.2%

2004/

06/01 4.3% 1.3%

2004/

07/01 4.4% 1.1%

2004/

08/01 4.4% 1.1%

2004/

09/01 4.2% 1.2%

2004/

10/01 4.3% 1.2%

2004/

11/01 4.2% 1.1%

2004/

12/01 4.3% 1.1%

2005/

01/01 4.1% 1.1%

2005/

02/01 4.3% 1.1%

2005/

03/01 4.0% 1.1%

2005/

04/01 4.1% 1.1%

2005/

05/01 4.1% 1.0%

2005/

06/01 4.1% 0.9%

2005/

07/01 4.0% 0.9%

2005/

08/01 4.0% 0.9%

2005/

09/01 4.1% 1.0%

2005/

10/01 4.1% 0.9%

2005/

11/01 4.1% 0.9%

2005/

12/01 3.9% 0.9%

2006/

01/01 3.9% 0.8%

2006/

02/01 3.9% 0.9%

2006/

03/01 3.8% 0.9%

2006/

04/01 3.9% 0.9%

2006/

05/01 3.8% 0.9%

2006/

06/01 3.8% 0.8%

2006/

07/01 3.9% 0.9%

2006/

08/01 3.8% 0.9%

2006/

09/01 3.7% 0.8%

2006/

10/01 3.7% 0.7%

2006/

11/01 3.8% 0.7%

2006/

12/01 3.7% 0.7%

2007/

01/01 3.8% 0.7%

2007/

02/01 3.7% 0.8%

2007/

03/01 3.6% 0.8%

2007/

04/01 3.7% 0.8%

2007/

05/01 3.8% 0.7%

2007/

06/01 3.8% 0.7%

2007/

07/01 3.8% 0.8%

2007/

08/01 3.8% 0.8%

2007/

09/01 3.9% 0.8%

2007/

10/01 3.9% 0.8%

2007/

11/01 3.8% 0.9%

2007/

12/01 4.1% 0.9%

2008/

01/01 4.0% 0.9%

2008/

02/01 4.0% 0.9%

2008/

03/01 4.2% 0.9%

2008/

04/01 4.1% 0.9%

2008/

05/01 4.5% 1.0%

2008/

06/01 4.6% 1.0%

2008/

07/01 4.6% 1.1%

2008/

08/01 4.9% 1.2%

2008/

09/01 4.8% 1.3%

2008/

10/01 5.1% 1.5%

2008/

11/01 5.4% 1.4%

2008/

12/01 5.6% 1.7%

2009/

01/01 6.0% 1.8%

2009/

02/01 6.4% 1.9%

2009/

03/01 6.6% 2.1%

2009/

04/01 6.5% 2.4%

2009/

05/01 6.9% 2.6%

2009/

06/01 6.9% 2.8%

2009/

07/01 6.2% 3.2%

2009/

08/01 6.3% 3.3%

2009/

09/01 6.2% 3.6%

2009/

10/01 6.4% 3.7%

2009/

11/01 5.9% 3.8%

2009/

12/01 5.9% 4.0%

2010/

01/01 5.8% 4.1%

2010/

02/01 5.8% 4.0%

2010/

03/01 5.6% 4.3%

2010/

04/01 5.3% 4.4%

2010/

05/01 5.3% 4.3%

2010/

06/01 5.3% 4.3%

2010/

07/01 5.2% 4.2%

2010/

08/01 5.4% 4.0%

2010/

09/01 5.5% 4.0%

2010/

10/01 5.5% 4.1%

2010/

11/01 5.6% 4.1%

2010/

12/01 5.2% 4.2%

2011/

01/01 5.2% 4.1%

2011/

02/01 5.1% 3.9%

2011/

03/01 4.9% 4.0%

2011/

04/01 5.1% 3.8%

2011/

05/01 5.0% 4.0%

2011/

06/01 5.1% 4.0%

2011/

07/01 5.0% 4.0%

2011/

08/01 5.1% 3.9%

2011/

09/01 5.0% 4.1%

2011/

10/01 5.1% 3.8%

2011/

11/01 4.9% 3.7%

2011/

12/01 4.9% 3.6%

2012/

01/01 4.7% 3.6%

2012/

02/01 4.8% 3.5%

2012/

03/01 4.8% 3.4%

2012/

04/01 4.8% 3.3%

2012/

05/01 4.7% 3.5%

2012/

06/01 4.8% 3.4%

2012/

07/01 4.9% 3.3%

2012/

08/01 4.9% 3.2%

2012/

09/01 4.6% 3.1%

2012/

10/01 4.7% 3.2%

2012/

11/01 4.6% 3.1%

2012/

12/01 4.8% 3.1%

2013/

01/01 4.9% 3.0%

2013/

02/01 4.6% 3.1%

2013/

03/01 4.6% 3.0%

2013/

04/01 4.7% 2.8%

2013/

05/01 4.7% 2.8%

2013/

06/01 4.8% 2.8%

2013/

07/01 4.6% 2.7%

2013/

08/01 4.5% 2.7%

2013/

09/01 4.5% 2.7%

2013/

10/01 4.7% 2.6%

2013/

11/01 4.4% 2.6%

2013/

12/01 4.1% 2.5%

2014/

01/01 4.2% 2.3%

2014/

02/01 4.2% 2.5%

2014/

03/01 4.3% 2.4%

2014/

04/01 4.1% 2.2%

2014/

05/01 4.1% 2.2%

EPI BRIEFING PAPER #384|SEPTEMBER 29, 2014 PAGE 3

(4)

job loss is associated with lower future earnings or other negative economic outcomes, and these adverse outcomes seem to persist even after the initial spell of joblessness ends, these outcomes are considered microeconomic scarring. This means we are not including the income declines that are contemporaneous with the jobless spell. It is trivial indeed to note that when people lose jobs, their income falls, and these income declines cause great economic distress. Scarring, however, implies something else: that capacity is diminished for an extended period of time even after the initial damage is healed (i.e., after the initial jobless spell has passed).

Because we are not including the damage inflicted by income declines that are contemporaneous with the jobless spell (this kind of damage is obviously correlated with the length of joblessness), it is not a foregone empirical conclusion that there is unique long-term damage to individuals and households stemming from a spell of LTU. This paper specifically addresses the question of whether or not the scars of long-term jobless spells are clearly worse than those of shorter job- less spells.

Finally, the paper highlights two channels through which a spell of LTU can scar workers. First, there could be a causal effect of extended LTU on workers’ potential productivity, as skills depreciate or professional networks erode. Second, the spell could be used as a signal by employers looking to sort potential hires in the job queue. While it may be statisti- cally rational for employers to use such a sorting device, the mere fact that they are doing so does not imply that we can make reliable inferences about LTU spells’ causal impact on worker productivity. We label the scars left by these two channels as productivity scarring and signal scarring. These are quite important to distinguish, as they have very different policy implications.

This paper finds that regardless of duration, involuntary job loss leads to significant and long-lasting economic damage to individuals and their families. Specific findings on microeconomic scarring include:

Excess unemployment during the Great Recession will likely lead to long-run wage losses just for displaced high- tenure workers (those who had the same job for more than three years) totaling more than $1 trillion over the next 20 years (or roughly $50 billion annually).

Research shows that workers who lose their job involuntarily experience worse health outcomes, and during severe economic downturns, these effects can lead to life expectancy reductions of 1 to 1.5 years.

According to rigorous studies, involuntary job displacement affects displaced workers’ children by reducing school achievement and even the adult earnings of the affected children.

Despite the deep and obvious damage done by any spell of involuntary job loss, there is very little compelling evi- dence that the scarring effects are worse for longer spells.

Apart from scarring effects, the primary economic damage that is larger for long spells of joblessness (i.e., those last- ing more than six months) is the lower incomes that result from unemployment insurance benefits being cut off, which occurs roughly around six months in most states.

There is growing evidence that employers’ hiring decisions may discriminate against those unemployed for long durations. However, this does not necessarily imply a causal linkage between extended durations and reduced worker productivity.

(5)

In short, there is little in the microeconomic evidence to suggest that long-term unemployment somehow hardens into structural unemployment that is not amenable to addressing through macroeconomic measures to boost demand. As such, policies that will increase aggregate demand are the best way to alleviate long-term unemploy- ment.

Macroeconomic scarring

We define macroeconomic scarring as the damage done to the economy’s estimated long-term potential output that stems from periods of elevated unemployment. The criterion that the economy’s long-term potential output declines is essen- tially equivalent to elevated unemployment leading to a rise in estimates of the natural rate, or the non-accelerating inflation rate of unemployment (NAIRU, henceforth). As before, we apply a more stringent criterion to scarring that is specific to LTU. Specifically, the damage must be greater when LTU is higher as a share of overall unemployment.

Finally, in regards to macroeconomic scarring, we also look for signs of irreversibility as a necessary criterion. That is, if extended periods of elevated unemployment (or LTU) lead to lower estimates of future potential output, this alone will not be enough to constitute a macroeconomic scar. Rather, we will also examine the evidence to see if this scarring effect can be sustainably reversed by an extended period of below-average unemployment (or LTU). If it can, we will then classify this as reversible scarring.

With respect to macroeconomic scarring, this paper finds:

There is some compelling evidence—some of it quite recent—showing that elevated unemployment (which tends to be accompanied by longer-than-average spells of unemployment and higher LTU as a share of total unemploy- ment) can lead to a reduction in the economy’s estimated long-term growth potential.

However, the damage done to potential output by an extended period of elevated unemployment and LTU tends to be reversed when the economy enters an extended period of abnormally low unemployment.

The fact that the damage done by extended periods of elevated unemployment and LTU can be reversed means, in our view, that the evidence for macroeconomic scarring stemming from a period of elevated LTU is quite thin.

Consequently, policies to reverse this damage should be a key priority.

Evidence on microeconomic scarring

The clearest finding from the literature on the scarring effects of unemployment is that the simple fact of an involuntary job loss causes significant economic damage, and that this damage lasts well past the end of the first jobless spell. Most strikingly, the fact of an involuntary job loss by a parent is associated with economic damage to the careers of their children. This evidence argues strongly that the cost of recessions is likely understated if measured simply in terms of foregone output.

However, what is much less clear is whether or not the scarring inflicted by involuntary displacement is worse for longer jobless spells. While a longer jobless spell is obviously associated with a larger cumulative income drop during the spell, it is not a foregone conclusion that longer bouts of unemployment result in more scarring—i.e., economic damage that persists after a given spell of joblessness is over. In fact, there is very little evidence that long jobless spells cause extra

(6)

scarring. Below we first survey the evidence on scarring inflicted by involuntary job loss of any duration, and then we note the (much thinner) evidence on whether longer jobless spells cause additional scarring.

Scarring from job loss of any kind

This first section documents the extensive evidence showing that any involuntary job loss is associated with very high economic costs, including clear evidence that such involuntary job loss can leave deep economic scars that persist well after the jobless spells pass.

Displacement and permanent wage losses

The most compelling recent empirical work documenting the long-run wage implications of involuntary job displace- ment is by Davis and von Wachter (2011). Davis and von Wachter (2011) investigate the Great Recession to estimate the impact of permanent layoffs among high-tenure workers (those who had the same job for more than three years) and the associated cumulative earnings losses. Using Social Security records for U.S. workers between 1974 and 2008, they measure how much the present value of career earnings falls due to job displacement. Perhaps their most important finding is that the costs of job loss vary significantly depending upon the labor market conditions prevailing at the time of the layoff.

They find that when the unemployment rate is below 6 percent, men displaced from high-tenure jobs lose an average of 1.4 years of pre-displacement earnings. However, this number essentially doubles when the unemployment rate exceeds 8 percent. The results indicate that for the 20 years following displacement, the present value of earnings falls by roughly 11 to 19 percent, depending on labor market conditions prevailing at the time of displacement.

Their evidence indicates that the cost of job loss over the Great Recession has likely been staggering. For example, as shown in Figure B, just under 7 million adults were displaced from high-tenure jobs between January 2007 and Decem- ber 2009, up from roughly half of that number during the much healthier labor markets that prevailed between 2005 and 2007. Additionally, because the displacements in the latter period occurred with aggregate unemployment at his- torically elevated rates, the cost per individual job loss was roughly twice as large.

Figure Cfurther illustrates the Great Recession’s impact on these high-tenure workers by showing, as a share of the overall labor force, the number of high-tenure workers who were displaced at any point in the three-year Displaced Worker Survey (DWS) sample period who remained unemployed as of the start of the next DWS sample period. This share jumped from 0.4 percent in 2008 to 1.6 percent in 2010.

Davis and von Wachter (2011) estimate that the average pre-displacement salary for high-tenure men laid off during recessions was $59,285 (expressed in 2013 dollars) between 1980 and 2003. If we take this estimate (which is quite conservative, given that annual earnings—particularly for high-tenure men—were likely higher before the Great Reces- sion than their average between 1980 and 2003), we can use their parameters to estimate the long-run wage losses likely accruing to the excess unemployment generated by the Great Recession. To estimate this, we start with the number of high-tenure layoffs before the Great Recession (as shown in Figure B, these layoffs totaled about 3.6 million between 2005 and 2007). Using this baseline, we calculate the excess high-tenure layoffs over 2007–2009 and 2009–2011 using the data in Figure B.1These excess layoffs stemming from the Great Recession total 3.3 million over 2007–2009 (6.9 million minus 3.6 million) and 2.5 million over 2009–2011 (6.1 million minus 3.6 million). Then we multiply these

(7)

FIGURE B VIEW INTERACTIVE on epi.org

Number of displaced workers, total and long-tenured, 1999–2011 (in millions)

* Long-tenured displaced workers are those who lost a job they had held for more than three years.

Source: EPI update of Borbely (2011, Figure 1) using data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics Displaced Worker Supplement

Number of workers (in millions) 9.9

4.0 11.1

5.3 7.9

3.8 8.0

3.6 14.9

6.9 12.5

6.1 1999-2001 2001-2003 2003-2005 2005-2007 2007-2009 2009-2011

Total displaced workers Total long-tenured displaced workers*

0 5 10 15 20

5.8 million excess layoffs (3.3 million plus 2.5 million) by three times the pre-displacement (average) earnings of this group (as previously noted, when the unemployment rate is over 8 percent, as it was during the Great Recession and its immediate aftermath, displaced high-tenure men lose roughly three years of earnings, on average). This yields the esti- mate that excess displacement and excess unemployment during the Great Recession will likely lead to long-run wage losses just for this group of high-tenure workers totaling more than $1 trillion over the next 20 years (or roughly $50 billion annually). In short, the scars left by the widespread involuntary loss of stable employment during recessions are quite deep.

Displacement and mortality

The effects of displacement go beyond simple labor market outcomes. Sullivan and von Wachter (2009) study the long- run effects of mass layoffs from the 1980s recession to examine the link between displacement and the health of dis- placed workers. They use earnings and employment data for tenured male workers in Pennsylvania between the 1970s and 1980s and subsequent death records between 1980 and 2006 to compare displaced workers’ subsequent mortality rates to those of workers who didn’t suffer job loss.

Following the methodology of Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993), Sullivan and von Wachter (2009) focus on workers with stable employment relationships; specifically, those who had the same principal employer for at least three years in the late 1970s. They argue that displacement is likely to be particularly unexpected and costly for this group

1999-2001 2001-2003 2003-2005 2005-2007 2007-2009 2009-2011 Total

displaced

workers 9.933 11.105 7.874 8.022 14.905 12.493

Total long-tenured displaced workers*

4.024 5.329 3.815 3.641 6.938 6.121

(8)

FIGURE C VIEW INTERACTIVE on epi.org

Long-tenured displaced workers unemployment rate,* 1984–2012

* The long-tenured displaced workers unemployment rate expresses, as a share of the overall labor force, the number of high-tenure workers (those who held the same job for more than three years) displaced at any point in the three-year Displaced Worker Survey (DWS) sample period who remained unemployed at the start of the next DWS sample period.

Source: EPI replication of Borbely (2011, Figure 4) using unpublished data from the Bureau of Labor Statistics Displaced Worker Supple- ment

1.2%

0.8%

0.5% 0.5%

1.0%

0.7%

0.4% 0.3%

0.2%

0.6% 0.7%

0.3% 0.4%

1.6%

1.1%

1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 0

0.5 1 1.5 2%

of workers. They hypothesize that the health effects of layoffs flow through two channels: (1) acute stress associated with a drop in earnings and increased unemployment, industry mobility, and earnings instability, and (2) chronic stress of displaced workers who can only find employment with lower mean earnings and higher levels of job and earnings instability. Sullivan and von Wachter’s (2009) results show a sharp increase in mortality in the short term immediately following job loss and a long-run increase in the probability of dying of 10–15 percent for the next 20 years. This increased probability of death translates into an average lifespan reduction of 1 to 1.5 years.

Displacement and children

Finally, the damaging effects of displacement even harm successive generations by scarring the children of displaced workers. To understand the long-term consequences of unexpected job loss for future mobility, Oreopoulos, Page, and Stevens (2008) examine the effect of firm closings on the outcomes of the next generation. They also follow the method- ology of Jacobson, LaLonde, and Sullivan (1993) to identify the impact of an exogenous employment shock (in this case, a firm closing).

The authors construct groups of men whose fathers had the same levels of permanent income and worked in similar types of firms prior to the 1980s recession, and then use the sons whose fathers were displaced as the “treatment” group.

Year Unemployment rate

1984 1.2%

1986 0.8%

1988 0.5%

1990 0.5%

1992 1.0%

1994 0.7%

1996 0.4%

1998 0.3%

2000 0.2%

2002 0.6%

2004 0.7%

2006 0.3%

2008 0.4%

2010 1.6%

2012 1.1%

참조

관련 문서

• Khan Asparukh가 이끄는 원 불가리아인들은 다뉴브 강을 건너 현 재의 불가리아 땅에 들어 왔으며 지금의 Shumen 가까이에 있는 Pliska에 수도를 정하고 비잔틴과 전쟁 후

-1396년 오스만 터키제국의 술탄 Bayezid I세는 불가리아 북부 다뉴브 강의 도시 Nikopo에서 십자군과의 전쟁인 Battle of Nicopolis에서 승리하여 불가리아를

Development of Bulgaria Граждани за европейско развитие на България.. Rosen Asenov Plevneliev

동 기한내 위반사항이 개선되지 않는 경우「사회적기업 육성법」제18조의 규정에 따라 사회적기업 인증이 취소될 수 있음을 알려드립니다... 동

Schl e ge l등 3 1 은 Whe r be i n 등 8, 30 이 제안한 정중구개부 제1소구치 부위에서 생검한 조직을 이용한 조직학적 연구에서 절치관 또는 c ys t i cl e s

2 0 0 3 년도에 추진이 시작된 교육행정정보시스템인 나이스( NEI S,Na t i ona lEducat i on I nf or mat i onSyst e m) 에 포함된 I T환경 하에서의 학교재정운용과

I EC를 사용하여 정제된 항세균 물질은 t r i c i neSDS-PAGE에서 하나의 band임을 확인 한 후 N-말단 아미노산 서열분석을 하였으나 실패하였다.FPLC s ys t e m을

• 불가리아의 소피아 대학교 한국어과는 이미 설립되어 있으나, 벨리코 떠르노보 대학교 한국어 과정이 운영중이고 바르나 자유대학교에도 한국어과가 생길 예정.