• 검색 결과가 없습니다.

Effects of Ownership Structure on Firm’s Technical Efficiency In the previous section, the relationship between the technical inefficiency of

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances in the Northeast Asian Countries:

3) Effects of Ownership Structure on Firm’s Technical Efficiency In the previous section, the relationship between the technical inefficiency of

firms and ownership concentration was examined, and estimation results summarized in the table above.

For Korean firms low ownership concentration was typically associated with low levels of technical efficiency as inferred by the estimation results above.

However, no clear relationship was found between the estimated level of technical efficiency and ownership concentration.

The statistical relationship between the estimated technical inefficiency and ownership concentration indicates that, in Korea, the technical inefficiency decreases as ownership concentration increases. In contrast, the technical efficiency increases as ownership concentration increases. Moreover, as debt equity, corporate size (assets size), and market share increase, the technical efficiency of firms tends to increase, but decreases when market competitiveness increases. Nevertheless, no statistically significant relationship was found between the estimated technical inefficiency and ownership concentration for Japan.

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 21

Figure 5. Ownership concentration and technical efficiency A) Korea

B) Japan

IV. Summary and Implications

In this research, the relationship between corporate governance structure and corporate performance was compared among three Northeast Asian countries, namely Korea, Japan, and China. Accounting corporate performances and technical efficiency measures were examined, and these variables were explained by their association with corporate performance measures and debt equity ratio, direct ownership, market share, log of total asset and concentration ratio of top 3 firms.

In the case of Korea, ownership concentration was shown to have positively affected all of the corporate accounting performance variables such as profit margin, return on shareholders’ funds, return on total assets, and return on

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 22

capital employed. All estimations were statistically significant. Furthermore, it was also found that ownership concentration positively affected corporate performance by influencing technical efficiency of firms.

Unlike Korea, in Japan, no positive effects of ownership concentration were found both on the accounting corporate performance such as profit margin, return on shareholders funds, return on total assets, and return on capital employed and the technical efficiency.

In the case of China, ownership concentration positively affected profit margin and return on total assets, while no positive effects of ownership concentration were found on return on capital employed and return on shareholders’ funds.11 Due to insufficient data on labor, the relationship between technical efficiency and ownership concentration was not examined.

It has been shown that the difference in the relationship between corporate performance and ownership concentration among the 3 countries can be attributed to the different corporate governance structures. The various corporate governance systems typical of industrialized countries are products of those countries’ histories, as well as their social and commercial cultures and specific institutional, historical and technological settings. In short, they are products of path-dependent institutional development.

Under the Korea’s Chaebol structure, controlling shareholders, who are the real owner of firms, exercise ownership rights even with small proportion of shares held. This is possible through the pyramid ownership control and cross-shareholding among subsidiaries. Consequently, the owner’s interests and corporate interests are identical under such a structure, thereby leaving controlling shareholder with less incentive to pursue their private interests. As a result, technical efficiency of firms may increase.

Korea’s unique corporate governance structure including the Chaebol structure as well as the huge disparity between corporate ownership and control has been pointed out as the main weakness of Korean economy that led to the recent financial crisis. Furthermore, there have been many controversies regarding the process of pursuing global standards through active corporate restructuring, specifically adopting Anglo-American corporate governance model, in recent years.12 On the other hand, it is a clear fact that corporate performance has

11 According to Xiaonian Xu and Yan Wang (1999), a typical listed stock company in China has a mixed ownership structure with three predominant groups of shareholders—the state, legal persons (institutions), and individuals—each holding approximately 30% of stocks. The five largest shareholders accounted for 58.1% of the outstanding shares in 1995 compared with 57.8% of Czech Republic, 79.2% of in Germany, 33% in Japan, and 25.4% in the US. Empirical analysis shows that the mixed and concentration of stock ownership do indeed significantly affect a corporate performance. First, there is a positive and significant correlation between ownership concentration and profitability. Second, the firm’s profitability is positively correlated with the fraction of legal person’s shares, but it is either negatively correlated or uncorrelated with the fractions of state shares and tradable A-shares held mostly by individuals.

Third, labor productivity tends to decline as the proportion of state shares increases.

12 The new corporate governance model is largely based on “the OECD Principles of Corporate Governance”.

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 23

improved as ownership concentration increased.

The corporate governance structure in Japan has also distinct characteristics.

The role of that main bank in corporate governance and inter corporate shareholding is well documented. Although Japanese banks rigorously monitor firms and have an enormous influence on the firms by owning their shares, the views toward the performance of firms in such a main bank system have not always been positive. Opposing views exist regarding the performance of firms in the main bank system.13

In China, state shareholders possess strong control rights over shares in listed company allowing them to exercise control even beyond their proportion of shareholding. Various governmental organizations acting as representatives of state shareholders influence firms enormously and hold control rights over organizing the board of directors as well as electing management. However since they have no incentives to manage state (national) assets and have insufficient capacity to monitor a large number of firms of which they are in charge, principal-agency problems tend to prevail and thus preserving the value of state assets remains difficult as well.14

It is likely that the difference in ownership structure (or corporate governance structure) among the 3 Northeast Asian countries has led to differences in ownership concentration and corporate performance. In Korea, for example, controlling shareholder managerialism could have influenced corporate performance as ownership concentration rises. On the other hand, it is not likely that state shareholders and main banks, respectively, have made much positive effort to increase corporate performance.

13 According to a survey by Campell and Keys (2002), there are two views on the role of main banks, but the main banks are likely to enhance the value of firms that have a tie with the main bank. Examples of important studies and their main conclusions are as follows: Aoki Patrick and Sherd (1994) highlight the significant role of governance by the main bank for Japanese firms.

The main bank monitors the firms effectively as they are well-informed about the firm (Diamond, 1984). The main bank’s equity stake in the client firms mitigate agency costs between creditors and shareholders (Prowse, 1990). The main banks sometimes intervene in the management of client firms that perform poorly by appointing bank employees to the board of directors in those firms (Kaplan and Minton, 1994: Kang and Shivdasani 1995; Mork and Nakamura, 1999). In the case of financial distress, the main bank acts as a guarantor for other creditors, reducing the cost of restructuring of the client firm (Hoshi and Kashyap, 1990). On the contrary, several studies showed that there are costs with having a main bank, which in turn leads to the reduction of firm value. Firms relying on the main bank for financing are likely to be constrained in raising additional capital when the banking sector as a whole faces financial difficulty (Kang and Stulz, 2000). The main bank can extract surplus from the client firms due to its monopolistic power of information production (Rajan, 1992). The main bank has an incentive to force the client firms to undertake low risk project (Weinstein and Yafeh, 1998).

Firms that do not depend on bank borrowing exhibit higher profitability than the matched sample of firms that have a main bank (Kang and Shivdasani, 1999). Main bank borrowing is negatively related to the firm value which is consistent with the view of the main bank extracting surplus from client firms (Hiraki, Inoue, Ito, Kuroki and Masuda, 2003). Several changes in Japan’s economic situation with which banks are faced have weakened especially the governance role of the main bank (Kotaro Tsuru, 2000).

14 Lee Keun and Dong Hoon Hahn (2002), “Chapter 7. Corporate Structure and Relationship between Chinese Firm and Bank,” in Chinese Firm and Economy, Bakyoungsa, pp.189-235.

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 24

Alchian and Demsetz (1972) view the nature of firm as a “nexus of contracts”.

From their point of view, if contracts between interest groups are made so as to increase efficiency, corporate performance should improve. In terms of incentive contract, meaning assigning firm’s residual control and residual return to the same entity, it can be explained that corporate performance in Korea improves as ownership concentration increases, but this is not true for Japan and China.

In Korea, ownership and control are not separated and therefore the proportion of individual shareholding is relatively higher than in Japan or in China. Also, the ownership of stock by financial institutions is not to exceed certain limits.

Thus, increasing ownership concentration implies that matching residual control and residual return in ownership structure is higher, which, in turn, contributes to enhancing corporate value.

In Japan, on the other hand, mostly banks and life insurance companies act as the principal controlling shareholders of firms. Main banks, although partly, tend to solve information asymmetry by participating in the management of firms. However, under Japan’s seniority system (or Japan’s hierarchical incentive system), no additional incentives are provided for dispatched managers. Hence, in terms of the corporate governance structure, matching residual control and residual return has little tendency to increase, thereby contributing little to increasing corporate performance.

Unlike Japan, in China, the state is usually the principal controlling shareholder.

In fact, most listed companies now initially were state-owned enterprises and have become listed companies. Although the country still sends state bureaucrats to firms, they face problems of degraded professionalism and moral hazard. This can be explained from the viewpoint of the theory of firm, as, in this case, residual control belongs to the bureaucrats, but residual return goes to the state instead. Thus, the mismatch between residual control and residual return and, as a result, concentration of ownership does little to contribute to increasing corporate performance.15

References

1. Aigner, D., Lovell, C.A.K., Schmidt, P. (1977), ‘Formulation and estimation of stochastic frontier production function models’, Journal of Econometrics 6, 21-37.

2. Alchian; Armen A. and Harold Demsetz (1972), ‘Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization’, The American Economic Review 62: 5, 777-795.

3. Aoki, M., H. Patrick and P. Sheard, The Japanese main bank system: An

15 In fact, Xu and Wang (1997) found that efficiency of firms decreased as the proportion of shareholding by state increased.

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 25

introductory overview. In: M. Aoki and H. Patick, Editors, The Japanese Main Bank System––Its Relevance for Developing and Transforming Economies, Oxford University Press, New York (1994), pp. 3–50 Chapter 1 . 4. Battese, G. E. (1992), ‘Frontiers Production Functions, Technical Efficiency and Panel Data with Application to Paddy Farmers in India’, Journal of Productivity Analysis 3, pp.153-169.

5. Battese, G. E. and Coelli, T. J. (1992), ‘Frontier Production Functions, Technical Efficiency and Panel Data: With Application to Paddy Farmers in India’, Journal of Productivity Analysis 3:1/2(June), 153-169.

6. Battese, G. E. and Coelli, T. J (1993), ‘A Stochastic Frontier Production Function Incorporating Model for Technical Inefficiency Effects,’ Working Papers in Econometrics and Applied Statistics No 69, Department of Econometrics, University of New England Armidale.

7. Battese, G. E. and Coelli, T. J. (1995), ‘A Model for Technical Efficiency Effects in a Stochastic Frontier Production Function for Panel Data,’

Empirical Economics 20, pp. 325-332.

8. Baur, P. W. (1990), ‘Recent Developments in the Econometric Estimation of Frontiers,’ Journal of Econometrics 46, pp.39-56.

9. Bothwell, James L. (1980), ‘Profitability, Risk, and the Separation of Ownership and Control’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 28/3:303-11.

10. Boudreaux, K.J. (1973), ‘Managerialism and Risk-Return Performance’, Southern Economic Journal, 366-72.

11. Bureau van Dijk Electronic Publishing (2003), OSIRIS DATA BASE.

12. Campbell II, Terry L., and Phyllis Y. Keys (2002), ‘Corporate governance in South Korea: the Chaebol experience’, Journal of Corporate Finance, 8:

373-391.

13. Chang, S. J. and U. H. Choi (1988), ‘Strategy, Structure and Performance of Korean Business Groups: A Transaction Cost Approach,’ Journal of Industrial Economics, 37: 141-158.

14. Cho, M. H. (1998), ‘Ownership Structure, Investment, and the Corporate Value: An Empirical Analysis’, Journal of Financial Economics, 47: 103-21.

15. Coelli, T., Rao, D.S., Battese, G.E. (1998), An Introduction to Efficiency and Productivity Analysis, Kluwer Academic Publishers, Boston.

16. Cosh, A. and A. Hughes (1989), ‘Ownership, Management Incentives and Company Performance: An Empirical Analysis for the UK 1968-80’, Discussion paper no. 11/89, University of Cambridge.

17. Demsetz, Harold and Kenneth Lehn (1985), ‘The Structure of Corporate Ownership: Causes and Consequences’, Journal of Political Economy, 93/6:

1155-77.

18. Diamond, D., Financial intermediation and delegated monitoring. Review of Economic Studies 51 (1984), pp. 393–414.

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 26

19. Dilling-Hansen, M., Madsen E.S. and Smith V. (2003), ‘Efficiency, R&D and Ownership – Some Emperical Evidence,’ International Journal of Production Economics 83 pp. 85-94.

20. Dilling-Hansen, Mogens, Erik Strojer Madsen and Valdemar Smith (2003),

‘Efficiency, R&D and Ownership – Some Empirical Evidence,’ International Journal of Production Economics 83, pp. 85-94.

21. Easterbrook, F. H. (1984), ‘Two Agency-Cost Explanations of Dividends,’

American Economic Review, 74, pp.650-659.

22. Fare, R., S. Grosskopf, and C. A. K. Lovell (1985), The Measurement of Efficiency of Production, Boston, Kluwer.

23. Farrell, M. J. (1957), ‘The Measurement of Productive Efficiency,’ Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 120 (Series A), pp. 253-290.

24. Forsund, F.R., Lovell, C.A.K., Schmidt, P. (1980), ‘A survey of frontier production functions and of their relationship to efficiency measurement’, Journal of Econometrics 13, 5-25.

25. Greene W. H. (1993), ‘The Econometric Approach to Efficiency Analysis,’ in Fried, H. O., C. A. K. Lovell, and S. S Schmidt (Eds.), The Measurement of Productive Efficiency Techniques and Applications, Oxford University Press New York, pp.68-119.

26. Greene W. H. (1997), ‘Frontier Production Function,’ Handbook of Applied Econometrics, Vol. II, Edited by M. Hashem Pesaran and Peter Schmidt, Blackwell, pp.81-166.

27. Greene, W.H. (1998), LIMDEP Version 7.0 User’s Manual (Revised Edition).

Econometric Software Inc., Plainview, NW.

28. Gugler, K. (2001), Corporate Governance and Economic Performance, Oxford University Press, Oxford.

29. Himmelberg, Charles P., R. Glenn Hubbard, and Darius Palia (1999),

‘Understanding the Determinants of Managerial Ownership and the Link Between Ownership and Performance’, Journal of Financial Economics, 53/3: 353

30. Hiraki, Takato, H. Inoue, A. Ito, F. Kuroki, and H. Masuda (2003), ’Corporate governance and firm value in Japan: Evidence from 1985 to 1998’, Pacific-Basin Finance Journal

31. Holderness, Clifford G. and Dennis P. Sheehan (1988), ‘The Role of Majority Shareholders in Publicly Held Corporations: An Exploratory Analysis’, Journal of Financial Economics, 20/1-2: 317-46.

32. Holl, P. (1980), ’Control Type and the Market for Corporate Control: Reply’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 28/4:443-5.

33. Holl, P. (1975), ‘Effect of Control Type on the Performance of the Firm in the UK’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 23: 257-71.

34. Holl, P. (1977), ‘Control Type and the Market for Corporate Control in Large US Corporations’, Journal of Industrial Economics, 25:259-73.

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 27

35. Hoshi, T. and A. Kashyap, Evidence on q and investment or Japanese firms.

Journal of the Japanese and International Economy 4 (1990), pp. 371–400.

36. Huang, C. J., and J. T. Liu (1994), ‘Estimation of a Non-neutral Stochastic Production Function,’ Journal of Productivity Analysis 5, pp.171-180.

37. Hwang, Inhak and Jung-Hwan Seo (2000), ‘Chaebol Governance and Reform in Korea,’ in Corporate Governance and Restructuring in East Asia, The 8th Seoul Journal of Economics International Symposium, August 25, 2000.

38. Jacquemin, A. and E. de Ghellinck (1980), ‘Familial Control, Size and Performance in the Largest French Firms’, European Economic Review, 13:91-91.

39. Jensen, M. (1986) Agency costs of free cash flow, corporate finance and takeovers. American Economic Review 76, 323-329.

40. Joh, Sung Wook (2000), ‘Effects of Corporate Governance Structure on Profitability of Firms’, The Analysis and Forecasts of Korean Economy, The 23th Annual Meeting, 2000

41. Joh, Sung Wook (2003), ‘Corporate Governance and Firm Profitability:

Evidence from Korea before the Economic Crisis,’ Journal of Financial Economics 68, pp. 287-322.

42. Jwa, Sung-Hee (2003), ‘In Search of the “Global Standards”: The Fallacy of Korea’s Corporate Policy’, Harvard Asia Quarterly, Vol. VII No.2.

43. Kalirajan, K. (1981), ‘An Econometric Analysis of Yield Variability in Paddy Production,’ Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics 29, pp.283-294.

44. Kamerschen, D. R. (1968), ‘The Influence of Ownership and Control on Profit Rates’, American Economic Review, 58: 432-47.

45. Kang, J. K. and A. Shivdasani, Alternative mechanism for corporate governance in Japan: An analysis of independent and bank-affiliated firms.

Pacific-Basin Finance Journal 7 (1999), pp. 1–22.

46. Kang, J. K. and R. Stulz, Do banking shocks affect borrowing firm performance? Analysis of the Japanese experience. Journal of Business 73 (2000), pp. 1–23.

47. Kang, Jun-Koo and Anil Shivdasani (1995), ‘Firm performance, corporate governance, and top executive turnover in Japan’, Journal of Financial Economics, 38: 1, 29-58

48. Kaplan, S. and B.A. Minton, Appointments of outsiders to Japanese boards:

Determinants and implications for managers. Journal of Financial Economics 36 (1994), pp. 225–258.

49. Keun, Lee and Dong Hoon Hahn (2002), ‘Chapter 7. Corporate Structure and Relationship between Chinese Firm and Bank,’ in Chinese Firm and Economy, Bakyoungsa, pp.189-235.(in Korean)

50. Kim, Juhyun (1992), ‘Study on Relation between Ownership Structure and Value of Corporations’, Financial Study. (in Korean)

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 28

51. Kim, Woo Taek, Daehong Chang, and Kyung Soo Kim (1993), ‘Empirical Study on Corporate Value and Ownership Control Structure’, Financial Study. (in Korean)

52. Korean Information Services Co. (2002), Raw Data on Corporate Financial Report.

53. Kumbhakar and Lovell (2000), Stochastic Frontier Analysis, Cambridge University.

54. La Porta, Rafael, Florencio Lopez-de-Silanes and Andrei Shleifer (1999),

‘Corporate Ownership around the World,’ The Journal of Finance, Vol. 54, Issue 2, pp. 471-517.

55. Larner, R.J. (1970), Management Control and the Large Corporation, New Jersey: Dunellen Publishing Company.

56. Leech, Dennis and John Leahy (1991), ‘Ownership Structure, Control Type Classifications and the Performance of Large British Companies’, Economic Journal, 101/409: 1418-37.

57. Lemmon, Michaell L. and Karlv V. Lins (2003), ‘Ownership Structure, Corporate Governance, and Firm Value : Evidence from the East Asian Financial Crisis,’ The Journal of Finance, Vol. LVIII, No.4, pp. 1445-1468.

58. Levin, S. G. and S. L. Levin (1982), ‘Ownership and Control of Large Industrial Firms: Some New Evidence’, Review of Business and Economic Research, 37-49.

59. Lin, Yi-min and Tian Zhu (2000), ‘Ownership Reform and Corporate Governance: The Case of China’s State-Owned Enterprises,’ in Corporate Governance and Restructuring in East Asia, The 8th Seoul Journal of Economics International Symposium, August 25, 2000.

60. Lovell, C. A. K. (1993), ‘Production Frontiers and Productive Efficiency,’ in Fried, H.O., C.A.K. Lovell and S. S. Schmidt (Eds), The Measurement of Productive Efficiency, Oxford University Press, New York, pp.3-67.

61. McEachern, W.A. (1975), Managerial Control and Performance, Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.

62. Meeusen, W., van den Broeck, J. (1977), Efficiency estimation from Cobb-Douglas production functions with composed error. International Economic Review 18(2), 435-444.

63. Mikkelson, W. H., M. M. Partch and K. Shah (1997), ‘Ownership and Operating Performance of Companies That Go Public’, Journal of Financial Economics, 44: 281-307.

64. Ministry of Finance and Economy (2000), Balancing Accounts of Institution Invested by Government in 1999 (in Korean).

65. Ministry of Planning and Budget (2000), Korean Public Firms (in Korean).

66. Monsen, R., J. S. Chiu, and D. E. Cooley (1968), ‘The Effect of Separation of Ownership and Control on the Performance of the Large Firm’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, 82: 435-51.

Ownership Concentration and Corporate Performances 29

67. Morck, R. and M. Nakamura, Banks and corporate control in Japan. Journal of Finance 54 (1999), pp. 319–339.

68. Murali, R. and J. B. Welch (1989), ‘Agents, Owners, Control and Performance’, Journal of Business Finance and Accounting, 16/3: 385-98.

69. National Assembly (2001), Data that Public Firms Respond to National Assembly's Request (in Korean).

70. Nickell, S., Nicolitsas, D., Dryden, N. (1997), What makes firms perform well? European Economic Review 41. 783-796.

71. Palmer, J. (1973), ‘The Profit-Performance Effects of the Separation of Ownership from Control in Large U.S. Industrial Corporations’, Bell Journal of Economics, 4: 293-303.

72. Pitt, M. M., and M. F. Lee (1981), ‘The Measurement and Sources of Technical Efficiency in the Indonesian Weaving Industry,’ Journal of Development Econometrics 9, pp.43-64.

73. Prowse, Stephen D. (1990), ‘Institutional investment patterns and corporate financial behavior in the United States and Japan,’ Journal of Financial Economics, 27: 1, 43-66.

74. Prowse, Stephen D. (1992), ‘The Structure of Corporate Ownership in Japan’, Journal of Finance, 1121-40.

75. Radice, H.K. (1971),’Control Type, Profitability and Growth in Large Firms’, Economic Journal, 547-62.

76. Rajan, R., Insiders and outsiders: The choice between relationship and arm's length debt. Journal of Finance 47 (1992), pp. 1367–1400.

77. Round, D. K. (1976), ‘The Effect of the Separation of Ownership and Control on Large Firm Profit Rates in Australia: An Ex[loratory Investigation’, Rivista Internationale Di Scienze Economiche e Commercial, 23: 426-36.

78. Schmidt, P. (1986), ‘Frontier Production Functions,’ Econometrics Reviews 4, pp.289-328.

79. Schumpeter, J. (1942), Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. Harper &

Row, New York.

80. Shleifer, Andrei; Vishny, Robert W. (1997) ‘A Survey of Corporate Governance’, Journal of Finance 52:2, 737-783.

81. Short, H. (1994), Ownership, control, financial structure and the performance of Firms. Journal of Economic Surveys 8, 203-249.

82. Slovin, M. B. and M.E. Sushka (1993), ‘Ownership Concentration, Corporate Control Activity, and Firm Value: Evidence from the Death of Inside Blockholders,’ Journal of Fiance, XLVIII, pp.1293-1321.

83. Sorensen, R. (1974), ‘The Separation of Ownership and Control and Firm Performance: An Empirical Analysis’, Southern Economic Journal, 41: 145-8.

84. Stano, M. (1976),’Monopoly Power, Ownership Control and Corporate Performance’, Bell Journal of Economics, 7: 672-9.