• 검색 결과가 없습니다.

In this paper we provide a valuation method for multi- asset derivatives with single jump regime-switching volatilities

N/A
N/A
Protected

Academic year: 2022

Share "In this paper we provide a valuation method for multi- asset derivatives with single jump regime-switching volatilities"

Copied!
6
0
0

로드 중.... (전체 텍스트 보기)

전체 글

(1)

Volume 27, No. 2, May 2014

http://dx.doi.org/10.14403/jcms.2014.27.2.237

PRICING MULTI-ASSET DERIVATIVES WITH REGIME-SWITCHING VOLATILITIES

Kum-Hwan Roh*

Abstract. In this paper we provide a valuation method for multi- asset derivatives with single jump regime-switching volatilities. We suppse that volatilities of assets are affected by an n-dimensional independent Markov regime-switching process.

1. Introduction

In Yoon et al.([6]), an analytic valuation method for multi-asset derivatives is investigated by using a Markov regime-switching volatil- ity model. They assume that the volatilities of the assets have two states and the changes of the states are governed by a 1-dimensional continuous-time Markov chain. This assumption means that the volatil- ities of assets are influenced by one market environment.

By reason of the empirical importance in financial markets, the valu- ation methods of derivatives are widely studied with a regime-switching volatility model.([1], [2], [5], [7])

In this paper we assume that the volatilities of underlying assets are affected by an n-dimensional independent Markov regime-switching.

This means that each volatility of asset is influenced by a separated independent market uncertainty. We use a single jump regime-switching process which is used in Roh([4]), Zhang and Zhou([7]).

Received January 17, 2014; Accepted April 07, 2014.

2010 Mathematics Subject Classification: Primary 91G20.

Key words and phrases: regime-switching, multivariate contingent claim, pricing derivatives.

This work was supported by the 2014 Hannam University Research Fund.

(2)

2. The model

We consider a filtered probablility space (Ω, F, {F}t≥0, P ). The fil- tration {F}t≥0 satisfies the usual conditions and is generated by n- dimensional correlated Brownian motion B(t) = (B1(t), · · · , Bn(t)) and n-dimensional independent Markov chain ²(t) = (²1(t), · · · , ²n(t)). And we suppose that Markov chains ²i(t) are independent of each other and also independent of the Brownian motion B(t). We denote the correla- tion between Bi(t) and Bj(t) as ρij for i 6= j ∈ {1, · · · , n}. In order to ease of the calculations we define the t-forward price of ith asset which is given by

Fi(t) = Si(0) exp

½Z t

0

(r(s) − di(s))ds

¾ ,

where r(·) is interest rate and di(·) are dividend yields. Throughout the paper, we regard r(·) and di(·) as deterministic functions.

And we suppose that n underlying assets prices are represented as (2.1) Si(t) = Fi(t) exp

½

Z t

0

1

2i(s))2ds + Z t

0

σi(s)dBi(s)

¾ , where the Bi(·) are correlated one-dimensional Brownian motion with a constant correlation ρij between Bi(·) and Bj(·) and i, j ∈ {1, · · · , n}.

We assume that the volatility σi(t) is affected by a continous-time Markov chain ²i(t). Also we assume that there are two regime states, high(H) and low(L) states. The volatilities σi(·) can take a value in iH, σiL}. And regime k switches into regime l at the first jump time of an independent Poisson process with intensity λik, for k, l ∈ {H, L}.

In other words, the random time τki of the leaving regime k has an exponential distribution with intensity λik, i.e P (τki > t) = e−λikt, k ∈ {H, L}.

It is assumed that a regime-switching model has a single jump over the life time of derivatives. Let the generator of a Markov chain ²i(t) have the following form,

(2.2)

µ −λik λik

0 0

with a positive intensity λik, k ∈ {H, L} and i ∈ {1, · · · , n}. Then the l-state is the absorbing state. This model is called a single jump regime- switching volatility model.

Proposition 2.1. Let σi(s) be governed by a Markov chain ²i(s) which have the generator, equation (2.2), where i ∈ {1, · · · , n}. Then

(3)

Z t

0

σi(s)dBi(s) is normally distributed with mean zero and variance ((σki)2− (σli)2ki+ (σki)2t, where σi(0) = σik and l 6= k ∈ {H, L}.

Proof. From the assumption of a single jump regime-switching volatil- ity model, the stochastic integral is derived as

(2.3)

Z t

0

σi(s)dBi(s) = Z τi

k

0

σikdBi(s) + Z t

τki

σlidBi(s), where τki is a random time of the leaving regime k.

Since σik, σli are constants, the equation (2.3) is linear combination of Ito’s integrals

Z τi k

0

dBi(s) and Z t

τki

dBi(s). Clearly, Z τi

k

0

dBi(s) and Z t

τki

dBi(s) are normally distributed with mean zero and variance τki, t − τki, respectively. Also, two normal random vaiables

Z τi k

0

dBi(s) and Z t

τki

dBi(s) are independent. Hence the equation (2.3), the linear combi- nation of

Z τi k

0

dBi(s) and Z t

τki

dBi(s) is normally distributed with mean zero and variance ((σki)2− (σil)2ki + (σik)2t.

By using the Proposition 2.1 we can simplify the asset price process, the equation (2.1) as

Si(t) = Fi(t) exp n

1

2(((σki)2− (σli)2ki+ (σli)2t) +

q

((σki)2− (σli)2ki+ (σki)2tYi(t) o

, where Yi(t) =

Rt

0dBi(s) q

((σki)2− (σli)2ki+ (σki)2t

, i ∈ {1, · · · , n} and k, l ∈ {H, L}. Given 0 ≤ τki = s ≤ t, Propostion 2.1 tells us that Yi(·) has a standard normal distribution.

Now we verify that an n-dimensonal random vector Y (t) = (Y1(t), · · · , Yn(t)) has a multivariate normal distribution from the next proposition.

Proposition 2.2. Let τkii, τkjj be the given jumping time which allow σiki and σkj

j to move σlii and σlj

j, respectively. Then the random vector

(4)

Y (t) is a mulativaiate normal with mean 0 and covariances Cov(Yi(t), Yj(t)) = ρijσkiiσjkj

q

τkiiτkjj + ρijσiliσljj q

(t − τkii)(t − τkjj), where i, j ∈ {1, · · · , n}, ki, kj, li, lj ∈ {H, L} and ki, kj are intial states of σi(·), σj(·).

Proof. Let eB(t) be an n-dimensional new Brownian motion which has mutually independent components. Then the random vector is decom- posed as follows:

µZ t

0

σ1(s)dB1(s), · · · , Z t

0

σn(s)dBn(s)

T

=



σk11 · · · 0 ... . .. ... 0 · · · σnkn

 · Σ1/2·

 Rτ1

0 d eB1(s) ... Rτn

0 d eBn(s)



+



σl11 · · · 0 ... . .. ...

0 · · · σlnn

 · Σ1/2·

 Rt

τ1d eB1(s) ... Rt

τnd eBn(s)

 ,

where Σ is the variance-covariance matrix of n-dimensional Brownian motion B(t).

Since Brownian motions eBi(t), eBj(t) and random time processes τi, τj are mutually independent for any i 6= j ∈ {1, · · · , n}, the cross-variation DR·

0d eBi(s),R·

0d eBj(s) E

t

¯¯

¯τikii jkjj = 0 for given jumping time τkii, τkjj. From Knight Theorem([3]), Rτi

0 d eBi(s)

¯¯

¯τikii are mutually independent random variables, which have a normal distribution with mean zero and variance τkii. Similarly, we can show that Rt

τid eBi(s)

¯¯

¯τikii are mutually independently normally-distributed with mean zero and varaince t − τkii.

Hence the random vector³Rt

0 σ1(s)dB1(s), · · · ,Rt

0σn(s)dBn(s)

´T has a multivariate normal distribution satisfying the conditions that the means of all components are zero, the variance of ith component is ((σki)2− (σil)2ki+ (σki)2t and the covariance of the ith and jth compo- nents is ρijσikiσkjj

q

τkiiτkjj+ ρijσliiσjlj q

(t − τkii)(t − τkjj).

(5)

The value of a European multi-asset derivative, V (T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T )) with expiry T is the expected present value of the payoff in the risk- neutral measure. The following theorem gives the pricing of multi-asset derivatives with a single jump regime-switching model.

Theorem 2.3. Let g(T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T )) be the payoff of a Euro- pean multi-asset derivative in initial states k1, · · · , kn ∈ {H, L}. Then its present value V (T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T )) satisfies

V (T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T ))

= e−rTE[g(T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T ))|σ1(0) = σk11, · · · , σn(0) = σknn]

= e−rT Z T

0

· · · Z T

0

E[g(T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T ))|τk11 = s1, · · · , τknn = sn]

× e−λ1k1s1· · · e−λnknsn ds1· · · dsn

Proof. Since the property of conditional expectation, the expected value of the payoff is converted as follows:

E[g(T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T ))]

=E[· · · E[g(T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T ))|τk11 = s1, · · · , τknn = sn]|τk11 = s1] · · · |τknn = sn]

= Z T

0

· · · Z T

0

E[g(T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T ))|τk11 = s1, · · · , τknn = sn]

× e−λ1k1s1· · · e−λnknsn ds1· · · dsn

Since the formula of Theroem 2.3 contains a conditional expectation E[g(T, S1(T ), · · · , Sn(T ))|τk11 = s1, · · · , τknn = sn], we can get a closed- form valuation of multi-asset derivatives only if we know the value of conditional expectation for given si. By Propositions 2.1 and 2.2, we can apply the results of constant volatility model to our regime-switching volatility model. For some derivatives, there is no closed form valuation such as the formula of Thoerem 2.3, since it is essentially a multiple integral problem. But it can be calculated using a various numerical approximation scheme.

3. Conclusion

In this paper, we have valued a multi-asset derivative when the volatil- ities of the asset price processes are modeled as single jump regime- switching processes with two states. Unlike the studies made extensively

(6)

on the regime-switching, very little attention was given to the relation of regime change in assets.

We assume that the each volatility of asset price process could change the regime state, independently. In a financial market, underlying assets of multi-asset derivatives can be in the seperated market. This could cause that the regime-switching of environment does not influence the other environment. In this regime-switching market environment we provide a valuation method for multi-asset derivatives.

References

[1] C. D. Fhu, I. Hu, and S. K. Lin, Empirical performance and asset pricing in hidden Markov models, Commun. Statist.: Theory Math. 13 (2003), 2477-2512.

[2] A. T. Hansen and R. Poulsen, A simple regime switching term structure model, Fin. Stoch. 4 (2000), 409-429.

[3] I. Karatzas and S. E. Shreve, Brownian motion and stochastic calculus, Springer, 2000.

[4] K. Roh, Pricing commodity futures contracts with a regime-switching model, J.

Chungcheong Math. 26 (2013), 787-791.

[5] K. Roh, Variance swap pricing with a regime-switching market environment, Manage. Sci. and Fin. Eng. 19 (2013), 49-52.

[6] J. H. Yoon, B. Jang, and K. Roh, An analytic valuation method for multivari- ate contingent claims with regime-switching volatilities, Oper. Res. Letters. 39 (2011), 180-187.

[7] Q. Zhang and X. Y. Zhou, Valuation of stock loans with regime-switching, SIAM J. Control and Optim. 48 (2009), 1229-1250.

*

Department of Mathematics Hannam University

Daejeon 306-791, Republic of Korea E-mail: khroh@hnu.kr

참조

관련 문서

The major contributions of this paper are as following: At first, in the paper we provide a short overview of the LoRa technology, describe the outdoor setup, show

In this paper, we fabricated reflective mixed- mode twisted nematic (MTN) LC film with ultra-thin quarter-wave-plate (QWP) films as substrates.. A single-polarizer MTN mode

This paper reports a method using molecularly imprinted polymers that are grafted onto the surface of carboxyl- modified multi-walled carbon nanotubes as the

In this paper, we define the cost of processing a computation-intensive task on the multi-core server in which the cores of the processor are divided into several voltage islands,

We have introduced a second-order accurate method for the discretization of the multi-dimensional Heaviside and delta functions on irregular domains in two and three

In this paper we propose an alternative approach for relay power gains in the network of the multiple relays with single antenna by using the approximation of cost function,

In this paper, we propose an efficient sparse signal recovery algorithm referred to as the matching pursuit with a tree pruning (TMP).. Two key ingredients of

In this paper, to understand the switching property of nematic liquid crystals (LCs) at the interface with a weak anchoring boundary, we investigate experimentally